ArrowArtboardCreated with Sketch.Title ChevronTitle ChevronEye IconIcon FacebookIcon LinkedinIcon Mail ContactPath LayerIcon MailPositive ArrowIcon PrintTitle ChevronIcon Twitter
Economy

The case for getting rid of high-denomination bank notes

Softer cashless route would hinder criminals, crack interest rate constraints

| China
Talk of abolishing large-denomination bank notes largely centers on preventing criminals from hoarding cash.   © Reuters

I previously discussed the merits of going cashless to enable central banks, including the Bank of Japan, to set interest rates at more negative levels. While that may not happen any time soon, eliminating large denomination paper currency notes -- a "soft" version of eliminating paper currency altogether -- is a more realistic prospect.

Pros and cons

First, abolishing currency eliminates the zero lower bound (or effective lower bound) on interest rates. Eliminating large denominations lowers the effective lower bound. This exists because currency pays a zero rate and has a fixed exchange rate with deposits that can pay any interest rate, positive or negative. The interest rate can therefore not go below zero by more than the "carry cost of currency" -- the cost of storing, insuring and safekeeping currency plus any cost of transacting using currency rather than other means of payment. Getting rid of only large denominations lowers the effective lower bound on interest rates rather than eliminates it. The ability of the central bank to set interest rates at more negative levels is valuable if, during future cyclical downturns, it is desirable to cut rates materially below zero to stimulate demand.

Second, currency notes are an inefficient means of payment. In financially developed countries many alternative and more efficient means of payment exist: transfers between bank accounts using checks, debit cards, prepaid cards, smartphones using Apple Pay, Samsung Pay or Alipay, credit cards and, possibly, still-emerging, digital cryptocurrencies like bitcoin, Ethereum or a possible future J Coin.

Third, the anonymity of currency makes it an attractive means of payment in illegal transactions and a desirable store of value for criminals. It facilitates tax evasion, avoiding capital controls, money laundering, funding of criminal activity and of terrorism. Bitcoin and other digital cryptocurrencies provide anonymity in a different manner, by encrypting the identity of the owner of a bitcoin "wallet" in a way that, up to now, cannot be hacked. Eliminating large denominations reduces the subsidy to criminal activity provided by anonymous currency.

There are two arguments against abolishing currency. First, there are likely to be households (and perhaps even some small businesses) that are not familiar or comfortable with the available alternatives to paper currency. The disappearance of currency could impose inconvenience and distress on those least able to switch to alternative means of payment. This is especially likely to be an issue in Japan, where the use of currency notes as a means of payment is much higher than in other industrialized countries. Cash payments in Japan account for 70% of all transactions by value. The average for other industrial countries is only about 30%.

Second, the anonymity of paper cash that subsidizes illegal activity also protects the citizen against an overbearing, intrusive state. This libertarian argument in favor of anonymity can, however, be addressed in other ways, as shown below.

Cash as a facilitator of crime is a real problem. At the end of 2016, the stock of currency in the U.S. was $1.463 trillion, an increase of $650 billion since 2007. That means over $4,500 per head of population. I know no one who holds that much cash. Professor Kenneth Rogoff has estimated that as much as half of dollar currency (by value) is held abroad. Some of this may be honest demand in countries with unstable currencies, but much of it is likely to be for illegal purposes. This view is supported by the fact that almost 80% (by value) of all currency notes is held in the largest denomination notes, $100 bills.

Japanese notes come in denominations of 1,000 yen, 2,000 yen, 5,000 yen and 10,000 yen. The largest denomination Japanese note is worth around $90. In the eurozone the largest denomination is 500 euros ($595), in the U.K. it's 50 pounds ($67), and in Switzerland it's 1,000 Swiss francs ($1,018).

In August 2017, the stock of currency in Japan was just over 100 trillion yen or 787,402 yen per head of population -- approximately $7,030. Even allowing for the high use of currency for (legitimate) transactions in Japan, these high average cash holdings raise concerns that part of it serves illegal activity.

Do central banks care?

Is any leading central bank focusing on reducing the role of currency by eliminating high denomination notes? Only the ECB has announced a small first step: the issuance of new 500-euro notes will cease at the end of 2018. The existing 500 euro notes will continue to be legal tender. There are no plans to stop issuing the next largest denomination, 200 euros, so the criminal fraternity will be only be minimally inconvenienced. Nothing is planned in the U.S., the U.K. or Switzerland. Only Norway, Sweden and Denmark, where currency notes are used very little in everyday transactions, are likely to go "cashless" in the foreseeable future. And in these countries it is the commercial banks that are taking the lead in phasing out the use of currency; the central banks play a passive role.

Some European countries are discouraging the use of cash in transactions by setting upper limits on the size of a transaction that can be made using cash: in France, it's 3,000 euros for fiscal residents; in Spain 2,500 euros; in Belgium 5,000 euros and in Greece 1,500 euros. It is unclear how these rules are enforced.

The reasons central banks are reluctant to "go cashless" or even to abolish the largest denominations can only be guessed at. It would clearly be unpopular -- and not only with libertarians. In addition, unless the central bank started issuing a digital currency instead, it would lose seigniorage revenue -- something that is likely to be unpopular both with the central bank and with its beneficial owner, the Ministry of Finance.

The best way to achieve the elimination of cash is to do it gradually and with ample lead time, starting with the largest denominations. The Bank of Japan could announce, say, that one year from today the 10,000-yen note will be demonetized, two years from today the 5,000-yen note will follow etc.

It would help if the central bank were to make available to each legal resident above a certain age, and to every legal personality, a checking account either with the central bank or guaranteed by the central bank, with the accounts managed by commercial banks, savings banks, other financial institutions, the post office, etc. To mimic currency notes, balances in these central bank accounts would be legal tender; there would be no overdraft facility. Funds could be transferred between "central bank accounts" and between a "central bank account" and other accounts using checks, wire transfers, debit cards, swoosh e-pay cards, prepaid cards, smartphones using Apple Pay, Samsung Pay, Alipay, etc. These universal central bank accounts -- a form of centralized digital currency -- should be provided free of charge. Interest could be paid on these accounts, say by linking it to an official policy rate. The interest rate on these central bank checking accounts could therefore be negative: the effective lower bound would either be eliminated (if all currency notes are abolished) or lowered (if only large denominations are abolished).

This centralized, non-anonymous central bank digital money could be combined with a central bank-provided decentralized cryptocurrency, using a distributed ledger technology like blockchain. Unlike bitcoin and other private cryptocurrencies, the central bank would set the exchange rate between money in the central bank accounts and the central bank's cryptocurrency. Because the holders of this decentralized digital currency would be anonymous, it may be difficult to pay interest on it. The central bank would still be able to set a negative official policy rate, say -2%, by increasing the value of money in the central bank account vis-a-vis the central bank cryptocurrency at a 2% rate.

From an economic and technical perspective, eliminating large denomination currency notes or all currency notes is easy. Politics is the obstacle.

Willem Buiter is chief economist at Citigroup and former member of the Bank of England's Monetary Policy Committee.

Sponsored Content

About Sponsored Content This content was commissioned by Nikkei's Global Business Bureau.

You have {{numberArticlesLeft}} free article{{numberArticlesLeft-plural}} left this monthThis is your last free article this month

Stay ahead with our exclusives on Asia;
the most dynamic market in the world.

Stay ahead with our exclusives on Asia

Get trusted insights from experts within Asia itself.

Get trusted insights from experts
within Asia itself.

Try 1 month for $0.99

You have {{numberArticlesLeft}} free article{{numberArticlesLeft-plural}} left this month

This is your last free article this month

Stay ahead with our exclusives on Asia; the most
dynamic market in the world
.

Get trusted insights from experts
within Asia itself.

Try 3 months for $9

Offer ends October 31st

Your trial period has expired

You need a subscription to...

  • Read all stories with unlimited access
  • Use our mobile and tablet apps
See all offers and subscribe

Your full access to Nikkei Asia has expired

You need a subscription to:

  • Read all stories with unlimited access
  • Use our mobile and tablet apps
See all offers
NAR on print phone, device, and tablet media

Nikkei Asian Review, now known as Nikkei Asia, will be the voice of the Asian Century.

Celebrate our next chapter
Free access for everyone - Sep. 30

Find out more